Read
Complete Document (pdf, 270.16 KB)
The federal program that provides insurance against the
risk of terrorism expired at the end of 2014. Without such a program, taxpayers
will face less financial risk, but some businesses will lose or drop their
terrorism coverage and economic activity might slow if a large terrorist attack
occurs. Last year, the Congress considered legislation to reauthorize the
program but shift more risk to the private sector. Other options include
limiting federal coverage to attacks using nonconventional weapons, and
charging risk-based prices for federal coverage. CBO has examined the likely
effects of different approaches on the private sector and on the federal
government.
The September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks resulted in
nearly 3,000 deaths and roughly $44 billion of insured losses (in 2014
dollars). In light of the unexpected and unprecedented losses from the attacks,
as well as the heightened uncertainty surrounding future losses, private
insurers subsequently reduced the availability of terrorism coverage for
businesses and commercial properties sharply. Policymakers were concerned that
without terrorism insurance, commercial developers in high-risk areas would not
be able to finance their projects, which would reduce new construction and job
creation and thereby slow economic growth.
In response, lawmakers enacted the Terrorism Risk
Insurance Act (TRIA) in 2002 as a temporary measure to provide catastrophic
federal reinsurance for terrorism risks without charging premiums up front.
Although no major terrorist attacks have occurred in the United States since
9/11, and thus the government has paid no claims, the threat of terrorist attacks
persists, and lawmakers reauthorized TRIA in 2005 and in 2007. The program
ensured that primary insurers continued to offer terrorism coverage on business
and commercial policies (including workers' compensation insurance), and it
might have reduced the need for federal disaster assistance if an attack had
occurred. But, as structured, the program exposed the government to a
significant amount of financial risk and subsidized policyholders (many of
which were large businesses).
How Did the
Federal Terrorism Risk Insurance Program Work?
TRIA required all property and casualty insurers to offer
terrorism coverage to their commercial policyholders. (Property and casualty
insurance covers businesses against losses from property damage, workers’
compensation claims, business interruption, and most liability claims.) The
federal government provided reinsurance to private insurers by agreeing to
reimburse them for a portion of their terrorism-related losses of up to $100
billion on commercial policies after an attack. Losses above that amount would
be uninsured.
Under TRIA, all types of losses from events certified as
major terrorist attacks by the Secretary of the Treasury were covered unless
such losses were excluded by the underlying property and casualty policies.
Nuclear, biological, chemical, and radiological (NBCR) risks are typically
excluded from property and casualty policies because they are difficult to
estimate and potentially much larger than conventional risks (such as large
truck bombs). The important exception to that exclusion is workers’
compensation policies: Almost all states require employers to purchase coverage
for workers’ compensation and require insurers to cover losses from all causes,
including NBCR attacks. Many policies also exclude cyber risks, such as those
associated with deliberate interruptions of computer systems, payment systems,
and power grids.
TRIA lessened the risk of losses to primary insurers by
shifting responsibility for some insured losses to all commercial property and
casualty policyholders and, in some cases, to the federal government. Insurers
paid no premiums for TRIA coverage but bore some of the risk of losses through
an initial deductible and then through a copayment above the deductible (the
government would have paid the remainder). For the first $27.5 billion in
insured losses (known as the aggregate retention amount), the government would
have been required to recoup its outlays after an attack by imposing a tax on
commercial property and casualty policyholders, including those without
terrorism insurance.
CBO estimated the effects of TRIA on the federal budget
on an expected-value basis, taking into account the estimated probabilities of
losses of all sizes, including the substantial likelihood that losses in any
year would be zero. In 2007, when TRIA was last reauthorized, CBO estimated
that total federal spending resulting from the seven-year extension would be
about $7.7 billion and that the net budgetary cost after accounting for
recoupment would be about $1 billion—small relative to the total exposure of
losses. The net costs were projected to be positive because CBO estimated that
attacks causing losses greater than the aggregate retention amount were
possible—although they would be very rare—and did not expect that the Treasury
would exercise its discretion to recoup federal outlays for additional losses
above that amount.
What Were TRIA’s
Effects?
Until it expired, TRIA was one factor that enhanced the
availability of terrorism insurance. Prices for terrorism coverage fell
steadily during the years TRIA was in force, partly because of the program
itself but also because of changing perceptions of terrorism risks and a
growing supply of insurance in general. With the lower prices and TRIA’s
requirement that insurers offer terrorism coverage, about 60 percent of large
commercial businesses and owners of large properties purchased such coverage in
2013, compared with less than 30 percent in 2003 (see figure below). Terrorism
coverage for workers’ compensation insurance, which almost all employers buy,
accounted for about 40 percent of total premiums for terrorism insurance in
2013.
The broader economic effects
of TRIA are unclear. By facilitating insurance for new construction and
business operations in general, TRIA may have helped speed the recovery in the
New York City area after the attacks on September 11 and may have benefited the
national economy as well.
However, any benefits to the national economy were probably small in recent
years, in part because at least some of the development that occurred in
higher-risk areas under TRIA would have occurred in lower-risk areas in TRIA’s
absence, and in part because many private insurers probably would have included
terrorism coverage—albeit at reduced policy limits and higher rates—in their
policies even without TRIA’s coverage. (Insurers that chose not to offer
terrorism coverage without TRIA’s coverage might have lost valuable long-term
relationships and other business with policyholders who wanted terrorism
coverage.) The program might have yielded more significant benefits to the
economy if another large-scale attack had occurred, because insurers and others
might, in TRIA’s absence, have reacted very strongly to the new evidence of
risk and reduced their economic activity.
The
TRIA program also had some economic drawbacks. Its reliance on recoupments
after an attack reduced the premiums charged for terrorism insurance,
especially for policyholders with high-risk properties. The spreading of risk
among all commercial property and casualty policyholders that occurred through
the rules for recoupments dampened incentives for insured businesses to
mitigate risks—for example, by relocating activities to areas of lower
perceived risk or by spending more on safety features—because the expected
reduction in losses would not be fully reflected in the premiums those
businesses paid. However, great uncertainty about terrorism risk makes the
benefits of mitigation intrinsically hard for businesses to assess, and there
is little evidence about how the change in incentives caused by TRIA affected
mitigation efforts. The government’s role in terrorism insurance under TRIA
also reduced the opportunity for private reinsurers and participants in capital
markets to insure against terrorism risks and left taxpayers bearing most of
the catastrophic risk. Although reinsurers’ ability and willingness to price
and bear terrorism risk have increased, they cannot compete effectively against
federal coverage that is available to insurers at no cost.
What
Are the Expected Effects of TRIA’s Expiration?
The
short-term effects of TRIA’s expiration on December 31, 2014, are expected to
be modest: Insurers currently have adequate capital (defined as assets minus
liabilities) to meet regulatory requirements and standards set by credit-rating
agencies; more important, both insurers and reinsurers have shown in recent
years an ability and a willingness to raise additional capital when presented
with profitable opportunities to cover more terrorism risk. For most insurers,
current potential exposures to losses from a terrorist attack are between 8
percent and 12 percent of their capital; they generally try to keep that
exposure to less than 20 percent. Because the subsidies that accompanied the
federal program have been lost, policyholders will face higher premiums.
However, most effects on policyholders will not be felt until their policies
come up for renewal, which will occur throughout 2015.
Looking
forward, if new legislation providing terrorism risk insurance does not replace
TRIA, most insurers will probably still offer terrorism coverage for
conventional risks—even though there would be no federal mandate to do so—lest
they lose business on other property and casualty lines. Even under TRIA,
insurers faced considerable risk exposure through that program’s deductibles
and copayments; facing greater risks, insurers will probably make more use of
private reinsurance and perhaps capital-market approaches to reducing risk
(such as securities that pay off if a specified insurance loss occurs) as well.
However,
the supply of private reinsurance and risk-bearing capital will probably not
expand enough to fully offset the loss of federal reinsurance, in part because
of the challenges in pricing the risk that was previously borne by the
government. As a result, policyholders will probably have fewer insurers to
choose from and will face higher premiums and lower coverage limits. Some
businesses will lose or drop their coverage. The effects on policyholders will
probably be felt more acutely in high-risk areas, and economic activity
(particularly construction) in such areas may be reduced. The decrease in risk
sharing resulting from reduced insurance coverage might be less efficient
economically.
The
resulting higher insurance premiums and increased involvement of private
reinsurers and capital markets are expected to have a number of effects on the
distribution of risk and on the behavior of insurers and businesses:
·
Risks
to taxpayers will fall. But taxpayers will retain some risk because, in the
event of a future terrorist attack, there would be tax deductions for uninsured
losses and there would probably be demand for postattack assistance resulting
from uninsured losses, as occurred after 9/11.
·
Risks
to private insurers and businesses will increase.
·
Private
insurers will probably try to take more account of policyholders’ risk levels
in setting their premiums and in offering discounts for mitigation measures.
However, the large uncertainties associated with terrorism risk will limit
insurers’ ability to charge risk-based prices.
·
Some
policyholders who would pay lower premiums or receive higher discounts if they
took actions to mitigate their risk will do so. Consequently, the expected
losses from terrorist attacks probably will be smaller, although the magnitude
of that effect might be quite small.
·
Businesses
that drop their policies (or are dropped by their insurers) and self-insure
instead will also have incentives to mitigate their risk. Conceivably, bearing
responsibility for their risks instead of sharing them through insurance might
lead businesses to mitigate excessively from a societal perspective.
Alternatively, some self-insured property owners might do less mitigation than
they would if they went through the insurance underwriting process and learned
more about their risks and ways to reduce them.
·
If
a terrorist attack causes large losses, insurance will probably be less
available afterward than it would have been under TRIA. (The inherently
speculative nature of predicting future terrorist attacks will limit the amount
of private capital that would be put at risk.) Consequently, new commercial
construction and credit flows might be impaired, which in turn could weaken the
economy.
·
Private
insurers will probably provide less workers’ compensation coverage because
private reinsurers will probably continue to be unwilling to offer coverage for
NBCR attacks (which cannot be excluded from workers’ compensation policies) and
because state regulations—such as those limiting risk-based pricing and
diversification of risks—will hinder other market adjustments. Instead, more
employers will probably be covered in the involuntary (or “residual”) market.
If
lawmakers choose not to reenact TRIA or create a new reinsurance program, they
could enact alternative policies to help businesses manage terrorism risk. For
example, lawmakers could revise the corporate tax code to allow insurers to set
aside tax-free reserves to cover expected claims from terrorist attacks, which
could increase the availability of terrorism insurance. However, doing so would
reduce federal tax receipts, particularly if regulatory oversight was
insufficient to limit insurers’ use of tax-free reserves to the purpose that
lawmakers intended.
The
expiration of TRIA will not lead to any change in CBO’s budget projections. The
projections made since TRIA’s last reauthorization in 2007 reflected the fact
that the authorization extended only through 2014. Consequently, the lapse of
the program’s authorization has no additional effect on the budget under
current law.
What
Would the Effects Have Been of S. 2244?
Before
the 113th Congress adjourned, House and Senate negotiators reached a compromise
that would have extended TRIA for six years. Under the version of S. 2244 (the
Terrorism Risk Insurance Program Reauthorization Act) passed by the House of
Representatives on December 10, 2014, insurers’ deductibles would have remained
at 20 percent of premiums they received for coverage in the previous calendar
year. Several other changes would have been phased in over the six years of the
reauthorization (see figure below):
·
The
amount of losses triggering payments under the program would have increased by
$20 million per year from a base of $100 million in the first year to $200
million in the sixth year;
·
Insurers’
copayments for losses above those deductibles would have increased by 1
percentage point per year from a base of 15 percent in the first year to 20
percent in the sixth year; and
·
The
industry’s aggregate retention amount would have increased by $2 billion per
year from a base of $29.5 billion in the first year to $37.5 billion in the
fifth year; in the final year of the authorization, the retention amount would
have risen to an amount equal to the average of insurers’ deductibles over the
previous three years (about $50 billion, CBO estimated).
S. 2244 would have retained the
mechanism for recouping some or all federal outlays through a surcharge (or
tax) assessed on all commercial property and casualty policyholders. The tax
rate would have increased from 133 percent to 140 percent of the difference
between total losses (up to the annual industry retention amount) and the total
amount paid by the insurance industry through its deductibles and copayments.
Effects on Insurance Markets
and the Economy
Because S. 2244 would have retained the basic structure of the previous TRIA program, its effects would have been broadly similar. Terrorism insurance would have continued to be widely available, insurance markets would probably have faced less disruption after a terrorist attack than they would have otherwise, and the economy might have stabilized more quickly after such an attack. Insurers and their policyholders would have borne most of the risk of losses from terrorist attacks through their deductibles, copayments, and recoupments, unless those attacks had resulted in losses significantly larger than those on 9/11. By relying on the recoupment mechanism, the government would have avoided having to set premiums for its coverage. However, that approach would have distorted insurance markets by recouping costs from all commercial policyholders, many of whom have limited exposure to terrorism risk.
S. 2244 differed from TRIA in
two key respects. First, increases in the copayments would have shifted more
liability to the industry for initial payments on losses. That shift would have
given insurers somewhat greater incentive to charge premiums that reflected
policyholders’ individual risks, thus giving policyholders somewhat more
incentive to adopt mitigation strategies, such as adding safety features to
buildings. Consequently, losses from future attacks and spending on federal aid
after an attack probably would have been slightly smaller than under TRIA. The
higher copayment rate would also have allowed a somewhat larger role for
private insurers.
Second, the higher aggregate
retention amount would have increased the federal outlays to be recouped after
a terrorist attack that caused more than $27.5 billion in insured losses;
indeed, raising the retention amount over time to $50 billion would have led
the government to recover all of its outlays in almost all cases, at least in
principle. However, the taxes required to achieve the recoupment targets after
a big attack could have been significantly higher than under previous law. The
recoupment mechanism has yet to be tested, and after a very large attack,
policymakers might be hesitant to tax all commercial policyholders, including
those without terrorism insurance, especially if the economy was weak.
Budgetary Effects
In line with estimates made by some commercial catastrophe modelers, CBO’s estimates of expected losses from terrorist attacks have fallen since 2007. CBO currently estimates that expected losses from potential attacks that would be covered under TRIA if it was extended would be about $2.1 billion in 2015 and would rise each year with projected growth in the economy. Those expected amounts incorporate a wide and unevenly distributed set of possibilities, ranging from no attacks in a year to highly unlikely catastrophic attacks.
In 2014, CBO estimated that the
six-year extension of TRIA under S. 2244 would have increased federal spending
by $3.0 billion over 10 years and increased net revenues by $3.5 billion over
that same period. (Estimated assessments exceeded projected claims over 10
years in part because claims can take several years to settle.) On net, CBO
estimated, S. 2244 would have reduced the deficit by $450 million between 2015
and 2024. However, the 10-year estimates provide an incomplete picture. An
additional $330 million would have been spent after 2024, CBO estimated,
producing a total reduction in the deficit of about $120 million (leaving aside
any potential effect on spending for disaster relief).
Changes in either the
recoupment scaling factor or the pace of recoupment would have affected CBO’s
estimates. If policymakers had set recoupment at 100 percent of the
government’s outlays under the industry’s aggregate retention amount while
keeping the bill’s requirement that all outlays be recouped by 2024, revenues
would have been lower and the program would have had an estimated net budgetary
cost of about $900 million. If, instead, policymakers had set recoupment at 140
percent, as in the bill, but allowed losses to be recouped over the 10 years
following an attack rather than by 2024, the estimated net cost over the
10-year budget period would have been about $1 billion higher (because less of
the expected recoupment would be received within the next 10 years). The
projected net budgetary cost over all years would have been roughly the same.
What Other Policies Would
Change the Distribution of the Financial Risks of a Terrorist Attack?
Some other approaches could
leave the expected net budgetary cost of insurance for terrorism risk roughly
the same as it would be under an extension of TRIA but would change how risks
are shared between insurers, commercial policyholders, and the government. One
such option would replace TRIA with a similar program that covered only NBCR
attacks. Another option would charge risk-based prices for federal reinsurance,
an approach that could be implemented in different ways. CBO evaluated those
two options—as well as current law (the expiration of the program) and the
option of extending and modifying TRIA as in S. 2244—on the basis of their
effects on the availability of private insurance; on the amount of risk borne
by the government (apart from any postattack assistance); on the demands for
postattack assistance; on mitigation incentives; and on the economy.
Limiting a federal program to
NBCR coverage would have various benefits and drawbacks compared with both the
expiration of TRIA and a broad extension of TRIA. Without a federal program,
private insurers are unlikely to provide much coverage for NBCR risks. By some
estimates, a nuclear attack could result in losses of thousands of lives and
hundreds of billions of dollars, particularly through workers’ compensation
insurance. Losses of that size would pose solvency risks for insurers, and
private reinsurance coverage for NBCR risks is largely unavailable because
there is little basis for estimating the risks with confidence. Thus, limiting
the federal program to NBCR coverage would have less effect on the availability
of insurance in workers’ compensation markets than would terminating the
program. It also would expose the government to greater risk than terminating
the program but significantly less risk than extending the program broadly. By
limiting the program to NBCR coverage, demands for assistance after an attack
would be less than if no program existed but somewhat higher than under TRIA.
Policyholders would have a greater incentive to mitigate conventional terrorist
risks, but insurance markets would be more prone to disruption after a
conventional attack than under TRIA and the economy would be likely to recover
more slowly.
Charging prices for federal
coverage that reflected the insured risks would encourage a bigger role for
private reinsurers and would increase policyholders’ financial incentives to
mitigate risks by reducing or eliminating the subsidies they received. That
option would lower the risk to the government by diminishing its reliance on
recoupments, which could be reduced, eliminated, or delayed. Implementing the
option—that is, setting prices that accurately reflect the value of federal
coverage—would be challenging, though various market-based approaches could be
helpful. For example, the government could obtain an indication of the market
value of its coverage by buying private reinsurance to backstop a portion of
that coverage, as is done by Australia’s terrorism risk insurance program. (In
contrast, the United Kingdom’s program charges insurers a percentage of their
premium collections in exchange for the government’s financial backstop,
requiring the government to determine the appropriate percentage. The
percentage in the United Kingdom’s program was recently raised from 10 percent
to 50 percent.)
Source: CBO
No comments:
Post a Comment